Lucas, M., Wagner, L.,
& Chow, C. (2008). Fair game: The intuitive economics of resource exchange
in four-year olds. Journal of Social, Evolutionary, And, 2(3),
74–88. Retrieved from http://137.140.1.71/jsec/articles/volume2/issue3/JSEC2-3_Lucas.pdf
This
is an interesting paper in an area that needs more research, namely, how
children perform in economic games. The typical questions go as follows: Are children
altruistic? Are they selfish?
The authors review and criticize some of the relevant previous
research. Murnighan & Saxon (1998) found that kindergartners
made larger ultimatum offers and accepted smaller ultimatum offers of candy
than did third or sixth graders. However, Lucas et. al argue that Murnighan & Saxon’s results are probably not valid
since they use a kind of simulated game, in which the child is asked to imagine
that another child offers such and such amount of candy (instead of actually
playing the ultimatum game). They also quote Harbaugh, Krause, & Liday (2003), who found that seven-year olds made and accepted
smaller ultimatum proposals than adults; and Hill and Sally (2006), who found
that 6-year-olds already make offers as fair as those of adults after repeated rounds
of play. Benenson, Pascoe and Radmore (2007), on the other hand, found that very
young children can be altruistic when playing dictator (4-year-olds donated, on
average, 25% of a stake of ten stickers to another classmate).
The authors also mention a
problem with some of the previous research: often, researchers make children
play with tokens that have no inherent value; children are explained that they
will be able to trade the tokens for other stuff later. Lucas et al. argue that
researchers should use items with tangible, real value for children, such as
candy, stickers or toys, since the use of “symbolic” tokens poses additional
cognitive demands on children and might affect experimental results.
Lucas et al. found, in their own study, that children made,
on average, offers of 4.7 stickers in the ultimatum game and 3.99 stickers in
the dictator game. That is, children seem to be making quite fair offers.
It is well established that adults give an average of 40% of
the money at stake in ultimatum. But there is a big difference between the 4-year-olds’
47% and the adults’ 40%. In adults, the mode
(i.e., the most frequent answer) is 50%, while some adults give 40%, 30% or
less, and almost no one offers more than 50%. However, some of Lucas el al.’s
4-year-olds offer more than 50%. They
call this phenomenon hyperfair offers.
There is a qualitative difference between adults and children: adults oscillate
between the fair (“half and half”) and the strategic (“less than half”). Many children,
by way of contrast, offer more than is
fair, more than half the stake.
“(…) the percentage of hyperfair offers (…) increased from
18% in the dictator game to 33% in the ultimatum game. Adults, in contrast,
almost never make hyperfair offers (only 3.5% of offers in Lucas, Et al., (2007)
were hyperfair).”
Lucas et al. also report that, in their study, children did
not seem to take into account the behavior of the other player in their
responses, even if it was unfair. In the dictator game, children did not change
the amount of their offer in response to receiving either a low or fair offer
from the friend. Children’s offers for the second game were also not affected
by whether the friend had accepted or rejected the child’s first offer.
The results of the dictator game suggest that children in the
sample are quite altruistic: “The adult average offer of 20% of the stake in
the dictator game (Camerer, 2003) is usually interpreted as evidence that
individuals have preferences for altruism, since proposers could offer less in
a dictator game without fear of rejection. With an average offer in the
dictator game of 40% of the stake, our sample of children made more altruistic
offers than adults.”
Children’s average offer of 4 stickers (or 40% of the stickers
at stake) doubles adults’ typical offer of 20% of the money at stake in dictator,
and does not seem to far away from the 47% children offered in the ultimatum
game. How do Lucas et al. explain these data? “(Children’s) ability to perform
a cost/benefit analysis was limited. They did not seem to appreciate the degree
to which they could “shade” their offers without penalty.” Thus, Lucas et al.
are assuming that children have the desire or goal of keeping as many stickers
as possible but they that their strategic thinking is deficient. “Children were
more generous than they needed to be and were limited in their ability to act
strategically in bargaining games in order to maximize their own benefits while
avoiding the costs of rejection.”
Lucas et al.’s conclusion: “children are quite altruistic”, “they
may have an innate sense of fairness and altruism.” This result is, in my
opinion, over-simplistic. Previous research in economic psychology has
established that adults are altruistic and fair to some degree, but also a little
bit selfish and strategic. Lucas et al. assume, therefore, that either children
are born altruistic, fair and strategic or they learn these behaviors along the
way. If research shows that children are completely selfish, then altruism is
learned. If it shows they are altruistic from the start, then it must be
innate.
I quote them: “We predicted that children would perform
similarly to adults in showing preferences for fairness and altruism.
Alternatively, and as some others have found, children could be less fair,
indicating that fairness must be learned over the course of development.”
They start with a binary opposition between selfishness and
altruism. In this approach, learning is seen as lineal, cumulative, unidirectional.
They start with some innate concepts and, while learning, children simply absorb
information from their milieu or copy adult models, until they reach the end-point.
There are other possibilities, however. For example: young children
might be neither selfish nor altruistic. They might be following other types of
reciprocity not related to the fair, contract-like, 50/50 reciprocity of
adults. They might use an associative reciprocity of the kind “I give a lot of
stickers to the other kid because I like to make friends” (see Faigenbaum, 2005), that are typical of children’s peer cultures
and of exchanges within the family. Such an approach dispels the apparent inconsistencies
of previous research: it’s not just that children are not yet able to think “strategically”.
They are not even interested in this kind of reasoning.
Associative reciprocity might explain why kindergartners make
large ultimatum offers and accepted small ultimatum offers of candy (Murnighan & Saxon, 1998) or why 4-year-olds can be so
altruistic when playing dictator (Benenson,
Pascoe and Radmore, 2007). It might also explain the results of Lucas et al.’s
own research, for example, why children give 40% of the stake in the dictator
game.
Some references
Faigenbaum, G. (2005). Children’s
Economic Experience: Exchange. Buenos Aires: LibrosEnRed.
Harbaugh, W. T., Krause,
K. S., & Liday, S. J. (2003). Bargaining by Children. Social Science
Research Network, 1–40. https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.436504
Lucas, M., Wagner, L.,
& Chow, C. (2008). Fair game: The intuitive economics of resource exchange
in four-year olds. Journal of Social, Evolutionary, And, 2(3), 74–88.
Retrieved from http://137.140.1.71/jsec/articles/volume2/issue3/JSEC2-3_Lucas.pdf
Murnighan, J. K., &
Saxon, M. S. (1998). Ultimatum bargaining by children and adults. Journal of
Economic Psychology, 19(4), 415–445.
https://doi.org/10.1016/S0167-4870(98)00017-8